Whatever might be possible in theory, actually existing capitalism has always relied on the globally uneven cheapening of labor and nature, the sacrifice of far-flung lives and ecosystems at the altar of relentless production, and the constant expulsion of populations alternately surplus and super-exploited...If capital and the state form the totality of the social order, then wresting control of the state—its representative, regulatory, financial, and legal institutions—is a means of contesting capital’s control over investment, production, and distribution.
Dessert wines are categorized by their exceptional sweetness. Achieving the desired levels of sweetness depends on the types of grapes, their natural sweetness, if and what type of bacteria is allowed to interact with the grapes, and when certain sugars and alcohols are added during the production process of the wine itself. The production of dessert wine requires a technical knowledge of the distilling process, available land for vineyards, facilities for the production and storage of the wine, and considerable labor to plant, harvest, distill, and bottle the wine. In 1685, Simon van der Stel, the son of an official in the Dutch East India Company was promoted from Commander to Governor of the Cape of Good Hope. The governorship came with a large estate, which van der Stel, eager to reproduce the vineyards he owned in the Netherlands, turned the part of the estate known as Groot Constantina into a winery.
A GUINNESS WORLD RECORDS™ title for the Most expensive Port wine sold at auction was set [in 2019] with the sale of the first Niepoort in Lalique 1863 decanter. Filled with the exceptionally rare 155-year-old vintage Port created in 1863 by the first Niepoort generation, Franciscus Marius van der Niepoort and contained within a meticulously crafted Lalique crystal demijohn decanter, it sold for HK$ 992,000 (approx. US$127,000) at Acker Merrall & Condit, Hong Kong.
While colonial routes of power focused on moving raw materials from the colonies towards the metropoles, contemporary international development methods are focused on identifying “under-developed” nations and conditioning foreign aid, FDI, and other forms of capital investment on the adoption and diffusion of liberal, market-oriented strategies—nearly all of which reproduce colonial North-South relations. Both private international and intergovernmental loans and investments focus on languages of growth and recovery in developing nations, even as they make claims of ‘greenness’.
Much of the rhetoric surrounding international development policy and foreign direct investment revolves around markets and globalization—and nearly all of the aid itself is about conditioning financial support from the nations in the Global North on “free market reforms” from leaders in Global South nations. For example, the IMF and World Bank offer a Green Bond program, aimed at securing money from fixed income investors that can then be lent out through the World Bank. The 2020 Impact Report on Green Bonds touts the 14.4 billion in funding provided to date through the program, with 4.6 billion dollars invested in renewable energy, 3.5 billion in clean transportation, and 1.1 billion in agriculture, land use, and forest and ecological resources.
Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) is a specific category of international capital flow in which a corporate entity from one country invests in a foreign corporate entity in another country with the intention of management. Determination of managing intention is predicated on at least a 10% stake in the foreign entity. FDI often takes the form of facility improvement, intra-company loans (loans that flow between financial entities under the same corporate umbrella), and mergers of existing corporate entities. The relationship between the investment, profits, and the loans between the companies is reported as the value of an FDI at the end of each fiscal year, which is then aggregated alongside all of the other investments and reported as a total sum for each country. FDI, as it is reported, is only a numeric value reflective of foreign investment that has occurred. Despite consistent cries from Western publications lamenting the scale of Chinese investment in Africa (see here, here, or here) the largest portion of Foreign Direct Investment into African nations comes from France, a vestige of colonial imposition that is still extracting value from now lost territories. Villainization of non-western investment across the world is likely to increase following the 2021 G7 summit as Western world leaders banded together to launch the Build Back Better World Partnership.
In 1980, FDI (adjusted for inflation) amounted to 84.34 billion dollars worth of investment. In 2019, that number was 1.9 trillion dollars.
The outward flow of capital is dependent on foreign nations having investment policies and structures that lend themselves to lucrative investment, resulting in the formation of many NGOs seeking to promote domestic policy that will attract FDI from wealthy transnational investors. The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) is an international organization whose aim is to “build policies for better lives [sic].”
Ultimately, the statistical representation of FDI makes it a difficult concept to evaluate. In some ways it is simply a measure of private capital flow internationally, which can point to different patterns in capital investment between the global North and South. On the other hand, it is the object of desire for some domestic policies in developing countries, rendering it a speculative device for future sustained growth. As Sumner highlights, attention should be paid to individual policies adopted by developing nations and their ability to attract investment schemes that better local lives in materially sustained ways.
Today, the particularities of Foreign Direct Investment are shrouded in its statistical aggregation. Data is reported on a country-wide scale, with breakdowns of inflow and outflow from each country. This aggregate reporting lumps together all corporations, regardless of their ability to stimulate local economic growth, provide materially better lives, or privatize industries and infrastructure in developing countries. All that is to say, FDI is a number; a number whose distribution patterns (spatially and temporally) reveal more about global market opportunities and national tax structures than about the efficacy and ethics of a particular investment.
Foreign Direct Investment differs from the actions of the World Bank and IMF in two fundamental ways. IMF and World Bank loans are not seeking a managing interest in investment projects and are offered from intergovernmentally funded pots of money. The World Bank and IMF are special entities under the umbrella of the UN. Each member nation, totalling 190 countries across the globe, has an individual quota that they must pay into IMF funds. Quotas are determined by weighted factors of GDP (50%), openness (30%), economic variability (15%), and international reserves (5%). All countries pay into the funds, which countries can draw loans from for disaster relief (climatic and health) or new development. The IMF distributes these funds through a series of funding programs: Rapid Credit Facility (RCF), Extended Credit Facility (ECF), Standby Credit Facility (SCF), and through explicit support for Low-Income Countries. Curiously, the IMF and World Bank loans, when taken together, covered much of the global south with few countries taking on loans from both entities. Thus, capital flows from wealthier nations paying into the programs as part of UN membership towards developing nations facing particular crises or who are seeking to continue development and bolster economic growth. These funds often focus on stabilizing countries that would otherwise be in perpetual states of unrest. As mentioned above, stability of the state is one of the key factors in predicting the presence of new FDI inflows into developing countries.
What we’re seeing with various forms of the financialization of primary commodity production is how socio-natural systems and biophysical worlds become packaged into assets that circulate in financial markets and become a source of revenue production in their own right –that is, how they become detached from reality.
While seemingly altruistic, these recovery practices are loans through and through, ones that tend to accumulate in regions of the world most vulnerable to the effects of the Climate Crisis. Dripping in irony, these lending practices aim to stabilize markets, one of the only identifiable predictors for FDI, even as market-focused concerns with growth are producing the effects of the Climate Crisis. In 2007, former World Bank Chief Economist Sir Nicholas Stern expressed the view of the World Bank quite succinctly: “Climate change is a result of the greatest market failure the world has seen.”